Open Access
How to translate text using browser tools
1 February 2009 Response from Lant, Ruhl, and Kraft
Christopher L. Lant, J. B. Ruhl, Steven E. Kraft
Author Affiliations +

Professor Fuentes raises a number of interesting points in response to our Forum article titled “The Tragedy of Ecosystem Services” (Lant et al. 2008), in which we present three approaches for dealing with the underprovision of ecosystem services: (1) the evolution of property rights, (2) reforming economic incentives, and (3) the development of ecosystem service districts. Addressing the second and especially the third remedy, Professor Fuentes argues, on the basis of Caplan (2007), that democratic political processes suffer from the “rational irrationality” of voters, derived from their lack of incentive to be informed on political issues and the systematic bias in the information they do use.

Caplan's thesis, however, is only one of many perspectives of voter behavior. Granted, voters and politicians today generally have a limited understanding of ecosystem services. That said, when scientists creatively engage voters and politicians—as they could do more effectively in demonstrating, for example, that lost wetlands could have significantly mitigated the storm-surge damages of $85 billion or more from Hurricanes Katrina and Rita (Colgan and Adkins 2006) and the $12 billion to $16 billion in property damages from the 1993 Mississippi floods (Galloway 1995)—constituencies can develop to protect and enhance such eco-system services. What voters perceive as rational, in other words, is not beyond the influence of new information effectively presented about the connection between the environment and their pocketbooks.

Where circumstances allow, we agree that the difficult work of constructing markets does provide advantages, including a measure of economic rationality for both providers and beneficiaries of ecosystem services that voters and politicians sometimes lack (see Forest Trends et al. 2008, Willamette Partnership 2008, Wunder et al. 2008), but there are many instances in which the public sector is the most appropriate ecosystem service provider. We also agree with Professor Fuentes's suggestion that increasing the size of private or public property holdings can lead to political inequalities, but the evolution of property rights cannot be left out of the picture. Developing common property institutions, ecosystem service easements, and other institutional designs for new property configurations embracing ecosystem services are worth exploring.

Ultimately, however, and despite its flaws, actively engaging the political process in the importance of ecosystem services to human welfare is necessary, if the externalities envisioned by Professor Fuentes are not to result in the accelerating degradation of natural capital and the consequent loss of ecosystem services. Constructed markets and new theories of property rights are not sustainable if they do not enjoy legitimacy in the political realm.

References cited

1.

B Caplan . 2007. The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies. Princeton (New Jersey): Princeton University Press. Google Scholar

2.

CS Colgan, J Adkins. 2006. Hurricane damage to the ocean economy in the U.S. gulf region in 2005. Monthly Labor Review 129 (8): 76–78. Google Scholar

3.

Forest Trends, Katoomba Group, and United Nations Economic Programme. 2008. Payments for Ecosystem Services: Getting Started—a Primer. Nairobi (Kenya): Forest Trends, Katoomba Group, and United Nations Economic Programme. (28 December 2008;  www.unep.org/pdf/PaymentsForEcosystemServices_en.pdfGoogle Scholar

4.

GE Galloway Jr. 1995. Learning from the Mississippi flood of 1993: Impacts, management issues, and areas for research. Paper presented at the U.S.-Italy Research Workshop on the Hydro-meteorology, Impacts, and Management of Extreme Floods; November 1995, Perugia, Italy. (28 December 2008;  www.engr.colostate.edu/~jsalas/us-italy/papers/12galloway.pdfGoogle Scholar

5.

CL Lant , JB Ruhl , SE Kraft . 2008. The tragedy of ecosystem services. BioScience 58: 969–974. Google Scholar

6.

Willamette Partnership. 2008. Increasing the Pace, Expanding the Scope, and Improving the Effectiveness of Conservation. [Extensive web materials on the mechanics of setting up a market in ecosystem services.] (28 December 2008;  www.willamettepartnership.org/Google Scholar

7.

S Wunder , S Engel , S Pagiola . 2008. Taking stock: A comparative analysis of payments for environmental services programs in developed and developing countries. Ecological Economics 65: 834–852. Google Scholar
Christopher L. Lant, J. B. Ruhl, and Steven E. Kraft "Response from Lant, Ruhl, and Kraft," BioScience 59(2), 102, (1 February 2009). https://doi.org/10.1525/bio.2009.59.2.21
Published: 1 February 2009
Back to Top